Basic Microeconomics by Professor R. Larry Reynolds, PhD - HTML preview

PLEASE NOTE: This is an HTML preview only and some elements such as links or page numbers may be incorrect.
Download the book in PDF, ePub, Kindle for a complete version.

producers/sellers. In a market economy, the inputs [land ®, labor (L), capital

(K) and entrepreneurial ability] are owned by individual agents who make

decisions about the amount of each input they want to supply. The decisions

of the producers determine the demand for the inputs. Remember that the

decisions of the producers reflects the preferences and ability

In the goods markets, each individual consumer will maximize their utility

MU

MU

MU

X =

Y = ⋯=

N , subject to: P Q + P Q + ⋯ + P Q ≤ BUDGET

P

P

P

X

X

Y

Y

N

N

X

Y

N

when:

This is an equilibrium condition. The consumer cannot alter their

expenditure and improve their welfare or increase their utility. Income

(budget), preferences (MUN) and the relative prices determine the outcomes.

The market demand reflects these conditions to the market. The demand

function is a schedule of the maximum price (reservation price) that buyers

are willing and able to pay for a schedule of quantities of a good in a given

period of time (ut), ceteris paribus. The supply function in the market reflects

the opportunity cost or producing each unit of output. It can be defined as the

minimum price (reservation price) that the seller will accept for each unit of

output. Market equilibrium is determined by the interaction of the buyers and

sellers.

268

14 Markets for Inputs and Distribution of Income

The equilibrium of the buyers and market equilibrium depends on the

income of the buyers. The way in which income is distributed in a system

determines the allocation decisions. The judgment about the criteria used to

distribute income has both an ethical and efficiency dimension. In most social

groups, it is considered desirable that income be distributed in proportion to

the contributions to the achievement of objectives. Clearly, most societies

make exceptions: most societies refuse to let individuals who are incapable of

making contributions do without resources and goods to support life. In

industrial societies there is a range of judgments regarding what things should

be provided. At one extreme few resources are provided. At the other extreme

a higher level of comfort is considered appropriate.

From an efficiency perspective, each factor should receive a share of

income in proportion to the factor’s contribution to the value of the output.

John Bates Clark (1847-1938) was one of the architects of the “marginal

productivity theory of income distribution.” In concept the idea is simple, in

practice it is difficult to measure the contributions of each factor to the

production process.

The production process was described by a production function. In its

simplistic form it is: Q = f(labor, kaptial, land, technology, . . . ) The

marginal product of each factor describes the contribution of each factor to the

production of the output. The marginal product of a factor can be described

as:

ΔQ

MP ≡

, the change in output ( Q ) caused by a change in F ( the factor )

F

ΔF

With the use of calculus the marginal products of a set of inputs can be

described as partial derivatives. Given a production function:

269

14 Markets for Inputs and Distribution of Income

Q = ALαKβ , the marginal products of the factors is:

Q

MP =

= AαLα1 K β

L

L

Q

MP K =

= AL α K β−1

K

If the marginal products are known and the relative prices of goods in the

markets reflect the values of the outputs, the value of each factors

contribution can be calculated as the product of MPF and the price of the

output. The marginal productivity theory of income distribution suggests that

the income share each factor of production should receive is determined by

the marginal product of the input and the price of the output. The change in

the value of the output associated with a change in an input is called the

value of marginal product (VMP) or the marginal revenue product

(MRP). Originally the VMP was used to describe the demand for an input into

production process for a purely competitive firm and the MRP was used to

describe the demand for an input used to produce a product where market

power (a negatively sloped product demand) existed. Most texts currently use

MRP as a generic term that covers both VMP and MRP.

14.1 A. THE DEMAND FOR INPUTS

T he demand for a factor of production is a derived demand. You do not

have a direct demand for an auto mechanic: rather you have a demand for an

automobile that functions properly. The demand for the mechanic is a derived

demand. You probably do not have a demand for 2X4’s (they really aren’t 2”

by 4”), you have a demand for a house that is constructed with the lumber.

The demand for an input is determined by the relative value of the good

produced and the productivity of the input.

270

14.1 A. The Demand for Inputs

The demand for an input can be derived by using the production function

(the MP for an input) and the price of the good. The marginal revenue product

is shown in Table IX.1.

Table IX.1 shows a short run production function. Capital is fixed at 4 units.

As labor is added, the output (Q or TP) increases at an increasing rate. In this

example the marginal product of labor (MPL) declines from the first unit. This

makes the MRPL or demand for labor less messy.

The constant price at all levels of output (PX = $11 at all output levels) is

the result of the firm being in a purely competitive market: the demand faced

by the firm is perfectly elastic.

The marginal revenue product is a measure of the value of the output that

is attributable to each unit of the input. The first unit of labor “produces “ 8

units of output (MPL = 8). These 8 units of output can be sold for $88

(PX=$11, MPL1= 8: so PX*MPL= 8*11=88). The maximum that an employer

would be willing to pay the first unit of labor would be $88. The MRP of the

second worker is $77. The second worker produces 7 units of output valued at

$11 each.

271

14.1 A. The Demand for Inputs

Table XI.1

Short Run Demand for Labor in Pure Competition

(MP

Kaptial (fixed)Labor (L) Q, TP

MP

L)PX

L

Product price, PX MRPL

4

0

0

$11

4

1

8

8

$11

$88

4

2

15

7

$11

$77

4

3

21

6

$11

$66

4

4

26

5

$11

$55

4

5

30

4

$11

$44

4

6

33

3

$11

$33

4

7

35

2

$11

$22

4

8

36

1

$11

$11

4

9

36

0

$11

$0

The MRP of each unit of input is the maximum an employer would be willing

to pay each unit of input and can be interpreted as a demand function. Notice

that if 35 units could be sold, 7 units of labor would be hired. The MRPL7 is

$22. The maximum the employer would be willing to pay the 7th unit of labor is

$

The MRP is the maximum the employer

(Wage)

will pay each unit of labour in a given

A

period of time given the productivity (MP)

and the price of the output (PX). At a wage

of WR, the firm will hire N workers. All N

workers are paid the same wage rate; i.e.

there is no price discrimination.

The wage bill or expense is shown as area

0NRWR, measure by NWR. the producer

W

R

R

surplus is area WRRA. The producer

surplus is not the same as profit. The

payment to the fixed factor must be

subtracted from the producer surplus to

calculate profit.

MRPL

0

N

L/ut

Figure IX.1

272

14.1 A. The Demand for Inputs

$22. Wage/price discrimination is technically illegal, all workers are paid $22.

The employer gains $66 on the first unit of labor ($88-$22), $55 on the

second, $44 on the third, $33 on the forth, $22 on the fifth, $11 on the sixth

and nothing on the seventh. This is shown graphically in Figure IX.1

The MRP of an input used by a firm with market power (a negatively sloped

demand for it output) is shown in Table IX.2.

Table XI.2

Short Run Demand for Labor For Firm in Imperfect Competition or Monopoly

Labor

(MP

Kapital (fixed)

Q, TP

MP

L)PX

(L)

L

Product price, PX

MRPL

4

0

0

$13

4

1

8

8

$11

$91

4

2

15

7

$10

$70

4

3

21

6

$9

$53

4

4

26

5

$8

$39.00

4

5

30

4

$7

$28

4

6

33

3

$6

$19

4

7

35

2

$6

$12

4

8

36

1

$6

$6

4

9

36

0

$6.00

$0

Note that the only difference in Table IX.1 and IX.2 is that he price of the

output must be decreased if more units are to be sold. This makes the

demand for the input relatively more inelastic.

273

14.1 A. The Demand for Inputs

$

B

WH

G

WR

H

0

J

L/ut

Figure IX.2

14.1.1 SUPPLY OF INPUTS

T he individual agent who owns the input will decide how much of a factor

they want to offer for sale at each price offered for the input. A worker must

decide how many units of labor (hours, days, weeks, years, etc) they will offer

for sale at each possible wage rate. The supply of labor is a function of the

wage rate, the value of leisure, alternatives available, taxes and other

circumstances. Generally it is believed that more labor will be offered for sale

at higher wage rates, up to a point. Owners of other factors of production

(land, capital, entrepreneurial ability) make decisions that determine the

supply functions of those factors. Figure IX.2 illustrates several possible supply

functions. The segment HGB is one possibility, it represents a supply where

the worker is willing to offer more labor at higher wage rates. The maximum

labor that will be offered for sale is at point B. At a wage rates higher than WH,

the supplier substitutes leisure for income and offers less labor for sale as the

274

14.1.1 Supply of Inputs

wage increases. Another possibility is a supply of labor that is represented by

segment WRGB. A horizontal segment at the prevailing wage rate is caused by

a worker or workers who refuse to work at any wage that is less than the

prevailing wage, WR.

14.1.2 MARKET FOR INPUTS

T he market for an

$

input includes all potential

buyers and sellers of an

B

W

input. The demand reflects

H

S

the decisions of the buyers

of the inputs and is based

G

W

on the MRP for the factor.

R

WL

The supply function

MRP

H

w

represents the decisions of

MRP

the factor owners to supply

1

the input at various prices.

0

T

L/ut

Figure IX.3 represents a

F

J

Figure IX.3

market for labor. MRP

represents the demand and S is the supply of L. The market equilibrium

occurs at point G where the quantity of labor offered for sale is equal to the

quantity of labor that is demanded at a the wage rate WR. J units of labor are

hired.

An increase in the productivity of labor or the price of the good produced

(PX) will increase the demand (MRP). A decrease in productivity or PX will shift

the MRP to the left (MRP1). If worker are unwilling to work for less than the

market wage, WR, the supply is represented by line WRGB. The level of

275

14.1.2 Market for Inputs

employment would fall to F units of labor. If HGB were the relevant supply,

unemployment would fall to T units and the wage would fall to WL.

If the MRP increased so the wage rate exceeded WH, workers would supply

a smaller quantity of labor in a given period of time.

14.1.3 INCOME DISTRIBUTION

I ncome distribution can be described as a functional or personal

distribution. The functional distribution of income describes the allocation of

income among the factors of production. The distribution of income among the

members of society, individuals and families, is called the personal distribution

of income.

Adam Smith, David Ricardo, Karl Marx and other early economists were

primarily concerned about the distribution of income among social classes that

were partially based on economic criteria. During the feudal era labor (serfs)

and land owners (aristocracy and church) were the important factors of

production. Generally, the social classes were the serfs, aristocracy and clergy.

Economic behavior was coordinated by a complex set of social institutions that

were based on deontological ethics (duty). Reciprocity and command were the

primary organizing mechanisms. Markets existed and were used in many

cases. Market towns and fairs were used to allocate some goods while labor,

land and many goods were allocated through obligations specified by tradition

and command.

The personal distribution of income describes the allocation of income

among economic agents. In most modern, industrial societies, markets are the

primary organizing institution of economic processes. Markets determine the

allocation of income as well as the allocation of scarce resources. Other social

276

14.1.3 Income Distribution

institutions such as welfare and philanthropy play a minor role in the personal

distribution of income.

Irvin Tucker ( mi

croE C

ONOMICS for Today , South-Western 2000, p 283)

shows the distribution of income based on the head of household. His data is

based on the Census data and is shown in Table IX.3.

Table IX.3

Income Distribution Based on Head of Household - 1997

Irvin Tucker, m

icroE C

ONOMICS for Today , South-Western 2000, p 283

Characteristic By Head of

Median Income

Household

All Families

$44,568

Male

$32,960

Female

$21,023

Age 25-34

$39,979

Age 65+

$30,660

Head non High School Grad

$25,465

Head High School Grad

$40,040

Head with Bachelor’s degree

$67,230

The information in Table IX.3 poses several issues. When considering

income distribution by age of household, there is a “life cycle” of a person’s

earnings and needs that should be considered. It should be noted that the

distribution of wealth and income are two related but different problems.

Another issue is the role of education and training. Disease and the industrial

revolution significantly altered the social classes and the distribution of

income. Technological change is a fundamental feature of modern industrial

societies and will change the nature and role of education and training in the

distribution of income.

277

14.1.3 Income Distribution

A “Lorenz Curve” can also describe the personal distribution of income. A

Lorenz curve can be used to show either the distribution of income or wealth

and can be applied to the world, a country or a sub category of individuals

(the military, lawyers, or . . . ). A Lorenz curve plots the cumulative proportion

of income units and cumulative proportion of income received when income

units are arrayed from lowest to highest.

The data for a Lorenz curve is shown in Table IX.4. (Irvin Tucker,

mi

croE C

ONOMICS for Today , South-Western 2000, p 282) The income

distribution is arrayed from lowest to highest. The data in Table IX.4 suggest

that the income distribution became more equal from 1929 to 1970 and less

equal from 1970 to 1997. The trends in income distribution are subject to

controversy. There are many forces that influence income distribution. It is

highly unlikely that the MRP is the single determinate of the income share

received by a factor or individual who