Basic Microeconomics by Professor R. Larry Reynolds, PhD - HTML preview

PLEASE NOTE: This is an HTML preview only and some elements such as links or page numbers may be incorrect.
Download the book in PDF, ePub, Kindle for a complete version.

proxies for their values then allocative or economic efficiency might be

represented as:

value of output

P Q +P Q

X

X

Y

Y

Allocative efficiency =

=

value of input

P L +P K

L

K

90

5.3.2 Production Possibilities Function

Q

Given the original PPF as line RA. An

Y

improvement in technology that impacts

H

H

only the production of xebecs can be seen

as a shift from RA to RB. An improvement

ls

in technology that influences only the

aw

R

R

production of Yawls would be a shift from

RA to HA. Technology that impacts the

production of both goods would be a shift

uantity of YQ

from RA to HB. These outward shifts are

sometimes cal ed “economic growth.”

A change in inputs could also be shown as shifts in

the PPF, a decrease in inputs would shift the PPF

inward toward the origin. An increase in inputs

would shift the PPF outward.

A

B QX A

B

Quantity of Xebecs

Figure 5.2

Allocative efficiency is not only influenced by the quantities of the goods

produced and quantities of the inputs used, but the relative values of the

inputs and outputs are also important. The benefits or value of an alternative

can be expressed as PXQX +PYQY. The costs of the alternative could be

expresses as PLL + PKK. Given a set of inputs and technology the solution that

achieves allocative efficiency is the highest valued output possible given the

inputs and prices.

A

Given inputs and a state of technology, the alternative sets of outputs are

53

B

shown by the production possibilities function. If all inputs are used to

50

produce Yawls (good Y, or QY), a maximum of 53 units can be

)

C

Y

produced. If the inputs are reallocated to produce 5 Xebecs (good X, or

Q 40

QX), it will be possible to only produce 50 yawls. At the output shown

ls (

D

by point C, 16 units of xebecs and 40 units of yawls are produced. If all

aw 30

inputs are used to produce Xebecs (QX= 32 at point G), a maximum of

32 units of X can be produced.

E

20

H

Given technology and inputs, all possible output combinations are shown

uantity of YQ

F

by all points that lie along and inside the line ABCDEFG. A change in

10

inputs or technology will shift the production possibilities frontier.

G

5

16

24 29 32

Quantity of Xebecs (QX)

Figure 5.1

91

5.3.2 Production Possibilities Function

Using the same production possibilities function as in Figure 5.1, allocative

efficiency can be described in Figure 5.3. In this example, the optimal output

alternative is that with the highest value. Since value cannot be measured

directly, neoclassical economists use market price as an approximation of

value. In order for market price to be a reasonable approximation, exchanges

must be voluntary exchanges of goods with exclusive property rights. If the

price of xebecs were $4 and the price of yawls were $2 the “value” of each

alternative identified in Figure 5.2 can be calculated. Alternative A is worth

$106, alternative B is worth $120, C is worth $144, D is worth $156, E is also

“valued” at $156. The output at alternative F is worth $144 and at G is worth

$128. These calculations can be seen in Table 5.3. The highest valued output,

based on market prices will lie on the PPF between alternatives C (valued at

$156) and D (also $156).

If the prices of the goods are accepted as the value of the goods, the

calculation of each alternative are shown in Table 5.1

If the price of good Y should rise to $3.50 (and the price of X stay at $4)

the alternative with the “highest value” is at point C as shown in Table 5.2.

The alternative that is allocatively or economically efficient is dependent on

a set of prices that measures value. We will explore the ability of the market

to accurately reflect values of outputs. It is also important to note that there

are many things that humans value that cannot be expressed as a market

price.

92

5.3.2 Production Possibilities Function

($106)

A

($120)

The PPF is determined by the finite quantity of inputs and technology. If

53

B

the price of xebecs is $4 (PX=$4) and the price of yawls is $2 (PY=$2),

50

($144)

at point A the “value” of good X is 0 and the “value” of good Y is

)

C

$106, the “value” of the output (given prices) is $106.

Y

Q 40

At point B the value of the output of good X is $20 ($4x5

($156)

ls (

units X), the value of good Y is $100 ($2x50 units Y).

D

aw 30

The value of output of good X and Y is $120.

($156)

($104)

At D and E the value of the output is $156. Some where between

E

20

H

alternatives D and E on the PPF the value of the output will reach a

($144)

P

uantity of Y

maximum. It is where the slope of the PPF is equal to X

Q

F

10

P .

Y

($128)

Any alternative inside the PPF will be valued at less than the maximum

G

value.

5

16

24 29 32

Quantity of Xebecs (QX)

Figure 5.3

93

5.3.2 Production Possibilities Function

Table 5.1 Allocative Efficiency and Value of Output

Value of

Value of output

Value of

output

Q

of X

output of Y

X

PX

QY

PY

(P

(P

XQX +

X QX)

(PY QY)

P

Alternative

YQY)

A

0 $4.00

$0.00

53 $2.00

$106.00

$106.00

B

5 $4.00

$20.00

50 $2.00

$100.00

$120.00

C

16 $4.00

$64.00

40 $2.00

$80.00

$144.00

D

24 $4.00

$96.00

30 $2.00

$60.00

$156.00

E

29 $4.00

$116.00

20 $2.00

$40.00

$156.00

F

31 $4.00

$124.00

10 $2.00

$20.00

$144.00

G

32 $4.00

$128.00

0 $2.00

$0.00

$128.00

H

16 $4.00

$64.00

20 $2.00

$40.00

$104.00

94

5.3.2 Production Possibilities Function

Table 5.2 Allocative Efficiency and Value of Output

Value of

Value of output

Value of output

of X

Q

output of Y

X

PX

QY

PY

(P

(P

XQX +

XQX)

(PYQY)

P

Alternative

YQY)

A

0 $4.00

$0.00

53 $3.50

$185.50

$185.50

B

5 $4.00

$20.00

50 $3.50

$175.00

$195.00

C

16 $4.00

$64.00

40 $3.50

$140.00

$204.00

D

24 $4.00

$96.00

30 $3.50

$105.00

$201.00

E

29 $4.00

$116.00

20 $3.50

$70.00

$186.00

F

31 $4.00

$124.00

10 $3.50

$35.00

$159.00

G

32 $4.00

$128.00

0 $3.50

$0.00

$128.00

H

16 $4.00

$64.00

20 $3.50

$70.00

$134.00

95

5.3.3 Pareto Efficiency

5.3.3 PARETO EFFICIENCY

At a technical level, economics provides a set of tools to aid in choosing

among competing alternatives. In 1906 an Italian, French, Swiss, engineer,

sociologist, economist Vilfredo Pareto (1848-1923) introduced the concept of

Pareto optimality as a means to undermine the role of utilitarianism in

economics. Instead, it became the foundation for what is now called benefit

cost analysis and its derivative measures of allocative performance such as

rate of return on investment and cost effectiveness.

Consider a community of individuals. Your task is to choose an alternative

to maximize the welfare or utility of the group. If there were an alternative

that would improve the welfare (or increase the utility) of at least one person

in the group without making any one worse off (decrease their welfare or

utility), you should choose to that alternative. However, if all the alternatives

that would make at least one person better off would also make at least one

other person worse off, you cannot know if that alternative would improve the

wellbeing (utility) of the group.

Pareto efficiency is the condition where all alternatives that would

increase the welfare of at least one person without decreasing the welfare of

others have been exhausted. There is nothing that can be done to improve the

welfare of anyone without making someone else worse off. In the PPF model

(Figure 5.4), Pareto efficiency exists at any point on the PPF once you have

attained that point.

96

5.3.3 Pareto Efficiency

A

Given the PPF, point H is not Pareto efficient: more X (Y) can be

53

B

produced with no sacrifice of good Y (X). A move to any output

50

combination identified in the triangle HEC is a Pareto improvement;

)

C

some one (or everyone) is better off and no one is any worse off; this area

Y

is Pareto Safe. A move to any point in the Pareto Safe area is a Pareto

Q 40

improvement or is Pareto superior.

ls (

D

aw 30

Once on the PPF (point D for example) any change to improve the

E

welfare of an individual (or group) who prefers good Y, would make

20

H

those who prefer good X “worse off.” To increase the quantity of Y, from

point D to point C, would require that less X would be produced.

uantity of YQ

F

10

G

5

16

24 29 32

Quantity of Xebecs (QX)

Figure 5.4

Pareto efficiency can be used as a criterion to decide whether to chose

an alternative. If a choice makes some one better off and no one any worse

off, it is a choice that will increase the achievement of the goal or end of

maximizing the utility or welfare of the group. This can be

Pareto Safe,” i.e. the output can be altered so someone is “better off”

and no one is worse off. Any change that increases the welfare of one person

or persons that does not reduce the welfare of another is a “Pareto

improvement” or Pareto Safe and will clearly increase the welfare or utility of

the community. Any alternative that results in a greater utility of at least one

person and no decrease in the utility of anyone can be referred to as “Pareto

superior.”

The problem is that this criterion tends to support the status quo. Almost

all choices that increase the utility of an individual or group will make others

worse off. Since a Pareto efficiency criterion is very restrictive, Pareto

Potential is may be used. This is the same as the benefit/cost criterion.

Pareto potential holds that if a choice or alternative makes one person or

97

5.3.3 Pareto Efficiency

group better off but others are worse off, if the “winners” or those who gain

can hypothetically reimburse those who are “losers” (or are worse off) and still

be better off, the alternative will increase the utility of the group. In a more

simplistic way, the benefits associated with the choice exceed the costs.

PARETO POTENTIAL, BENEFIT/COST AND MARGINAL ANALYSIS

The Pareto potential criterion for decision making is the foundation of

analysis that use benefit/cost, cost effectiveness and rate of return for

decision making.

Marginal Analysis

The process of making decisions is like the proverb “The longest journey

begins with the first step.” Or like the question posed by Albert Camus (1913-

1960) about the individual deciding each day about suicide or continuing life.

The individual taking a journey must make the decision about taking the first

step before they decide on the second. In Camus’ case, one must decide not

to committee suicide before you tackle the rest of the day.

Decisions in economics are always made at the “margin.” A decision to

change one variable will cause a change in some other related variable. An act

or choice will have benefits and costs associated with that act. An increase in

the production of xebecs may require a reduction in the production of Yawls:

the benefit is more xebecs, the cost is fewer yawls.

A change in the price of a good will change the quantity sold, a change in

the quantity sold will change the total revenue collected. The change in total

revenue caused by a change in units sold is called marginal revenue. The

marginal concept is applied to a wide variety of relationships. In principles of

economics, these are usually described as a “one unit” change in the

variables. The Greek letter delta, ∆ is used to identify a change calculated by

98

5.3.3 Pareto Efficiency

subtraction. In other cases, a derivative (d) or partial derivative (∂) will be

used to denote a change that approaches 0.

The use of marginal is applied to many economic relationships. In fact, the

early period of the development of microeconomics (mid to late 19th century)

was called the “marginalist revolution.” Below are some definitions of several

useful marginal relationships.

Marginal Cost (MC)

MC is defined as the change in Total Cost (TC) or variable cost (VC) caused by

a one unit change in the quantity produced, output (Q). MC represents

opportunity cost.

ΔTC

ΔVC

MC =

=

Equation 5.3

ΔQ

ΔQ

Marginal Benefit (MB)

MB is defined as the change in total benefit (TB) caused by a one unit change

in quantity consumed (Q).

ΔTB

MB = ΔQ

Equation 5.4

Marginal Utility (MU)

ΔTU

MU =

Equation 5.5

ΔQ

MU is the change in utility caused by a change in quantity consumed (Q)

CHOICE AND MARGINAL ANALYSIS

99

5.3.3 Pareto Efficiency

If Pareto Potential or the Benefit/Cost criteria are to be used for decision-

making, the rule is quite simple: if the benefits associated with a choice (or

alternative) exceed the costs associated with that choice, then the choice will

increase net benefits. If the costs of an alternative exceed the benefits of that

alternative, then that alternative is not a good choice.

EXAMPLE BENEFIT/COST USING MARGINAL ANALYSIS

Using the example PPF presented in Figure 5.5 (Same PPF as in 5.1, 5.3,

5.4 )

Consider the PPF in Figure 5.5: Xebecs are priced at $4 (PX= $4) and

yawls are $3.50 (PY = $3.50). If the initial output were where QX= 16 and QY

= 20, which is represented at point H. At these prices, the output of xebecs is

“worth” $64 and yawls are worth $70. The “value” of the output alternative

identified at point H is $134.

A

Original allocation is at H (QX=16, QY=20);

53

B

PX = $4 and PY = $3.50

50

Alternative E (C, D or any choice in triangle HEC) has no MC, the output of X or

)

C

Y

Y or both X and Y increases so the MB is positive. The B/C ratio of any

Q 40

alternative is grater than one, the MB>MC.

ls (

D

If production were at point D (QX=24, QY=30), a choice of alternative C would

aw 30

result in QX=16, QY=40, 8 units of X are traded for 10 units of Y. Six fewer units

of X at $4 each is a MC of $24. The MB is 10 additional units of Y at $3.50 each

E

H

or $$35. The MB>MC, The B/C ratio >1, the net benefits will increase by $11 by

20

selecting alternative C over D. Alternative C is worth

uantity of YQ

F

10

G

5

16

24 29 32

Quantity of Xebecs (QX)

Figure 5.5

100

5.3.3 Pareto Efficiency

Ranking of Alternative H with Alternative E

If alternative E were chosen over alternative H, 13 additional units of

xebecs would be produced (29-16=13). This is the marginal benefit (MB) of

the choice of reallocating resources from alternative H to E. If xebecs were

valued at $4 each, that would be a MB of $52 in monetary terms. This can be

viewed as a move from row H to row E in Table 5.3

Table 5.3

Allocative Efficiency and Value of Output

Value of

Value of

Value of

Alte QX

PX

output of X QY

PY

output of Y

output

rnat

(PXQX)

(PYQY)

(PXQX + PYQY)

ive

A 0

$4.00

$0.00

53 $3.50

$185.50

$185.50

B 5

$4.00

$20.00

50 $3.50

$175.00

$195.00

C 16 $4.00

$64.00

40 $3.50

$140.00

$204.00

D 24 $4.00

$96.00

30 $3.50

$105.00

$201.00

E 29 $4.00

$116.00

20 $3.50

$70.00

$186.00

F 31 $4.00

$124.00

10 $3.50

$35.00

$159.00

This reallocation of resources would not reduce the output of yawls, so the

marginal cost of the reallocation is 0. Since the MB > MC, the reallocation or

inputs to move the output alternative from H to E would be an improvement in

the achievement of the objective (producing the highest valued output). The

output of xebecs and yawls at point E is $186 (134 + 52: the value of the

output at H added to the MB of reallocation of inputs)

The relative prices of xebecs and yawls are irrelevant since the marginal

cost (MC) is zero. Any increased production of xebecs at any positive price

would be a Pareto improvement. A reallocation to point D, C or any output

combination that lies in the triangle HEC would be a Pareto improvement (or

Pareto superior to the allocation at point H).

101

5.3.3 Pareto Efficiency

Ranking of Alternative E with Alternative F

If the current output were at point E (QX= 29 and QY = 20), and alternative

F (QX= 31 and QY = 10) is considered. The marginal benefit (the benefit

associated with reallocating resources to point F) would be an additional 3

units of xebecs (31-29=3). At $4 each this is a MB of $12 in monetary terms.

However, the reallocation of resources from H to F requires a sacrifice or MC

of 10 units of yawls (20-10=10). At a price of $3.50 the MC is $35 in

monetary value. The MC = 35: MB = 12. A reallocation of inputs to move from

point E to point F would be trading $12 for $35: not a good idea.

Ranking of Alternative E and Alternative D

A reallocation of resources from alternative E to alternative D would result

in an increased output of 10 yawls. At a price of $3.50, the MB is $35. This

reallocation reduces the output of xebecs from 29 to 24, a marginal cost of 5

units of xebecs. At $4 each this is a MC of $20. Since the MB > MC (35 > 20),

the reallocation of inputs from the production of the output at point E to point

B is justified by our benefit/cost criterion. Notice that the net gain to society is

$15, so point D is “worth” $15 more than the output at point E. D is “valued”

at