Rhetoric and Practice of Reward Management by Rosario Longo - HTML preview

PLEASE NOTE: This is an HTML preview only and some elements such as links or page numbers may be incorrect.
Download the book in PDF, ePub, Kindle for a complete version.

Courts, at least in the UK, openly recognise the effects played by labour market forces

over pay. During the proceedings relating to the case Newcastle Upon Tyne NHS

Hospitals Trust v Armstrong & Ors, Mr. Underhill (2010), Judge of the UKEAT (UK

Employment Appeal Tribunal), referring to Rainey v Greater Glasgow Health Board case,

maintained that “it is well-established that a … defence based on market forces is

admissible in principle.” The same viewpoint was practically expressed by the European

Court of Justice when examining the case Enderby v Frenchay Health Authority, brought

before it by the Court of Appeal of England and Wales. The ECJ basically maintained that

the proportion of pay increases attributable to market forces can be accepted provided

that “the pay differential is objectively justified to the extent of that proportion.” The ECJ

also upheld that it is the national Court which has to assess whether and for which

proportion salary differences can be attributable to market forces (Longo, 2012).

This court case clearly highlights the circumstance that when a higher-than-the-

standard-grade salary level is granted to an individual on account of market forces, it

also needs to be determined whether the labour market pressures justify the whole

additional payment. In other words, whenever market forces supplements are conceded

they have to be proportionate to the recruitment difficulties and cannot be higher than

reasonably suggested by the pressures coming from the labour market.

It is hence admissible that, in presence of exceptional, uncommon circumstances, jobs of

equal value could be paid differently by means of market forces supplements payment.

Nonetheless, employers should be extremely careful and ready to show and provide

documentary evidence, if and when required, of the objective grounds justifying the

application of market forces supplements. As anticipated above, this will clearly reveal to

be crucial in the event a pay discrimination claim should be brought before a Court.

Prior to concede a market forces supplement, employers should always strive to recruit

and retain quality staff offering salaries encompassed in the salary range associated with

the relevant job grade. Only once all of the attempts made have revealed to be

unproductive, employers should consider offering market forces supplements. Difficulties

in attracting and retaining quality staff have to be verifiable, as well as the attempts to

having had recourse to possibly improved recruitment and retention approaches (Longo,

2012).

The circumstance that the supplement is regularly assessed and reviewed will also turn

to be eventually useful in front of a Court. This will contribute to provide evidence that

market forces defence is not an excuse used to justify salary differences, but that it is

actually a consequence of the labour market pressures, and that this is actually why the

labour market is constantly monitored and the supplement regularly assessed and

reviewed.

232

Rating and ranking jobs

An additional important aspect, also emerged in the Enderby v Frenchay Health Authority

case, is that employers should always be able to keep separate the salary related to the

job grade and that associated with the market forces in order to eventually enable the

Court to determine the impact of the latter over the former.

Checklist

Employers offering market forces supplements should both ensure that some activities

will regularly be carried out and that some other aspects constantly monitored.

The market forces element should be kept separated from fixed pay and clear evidence

of this should be given in the salary slip of the individual(s) concerned.

All of the documentary evidence which have accounted for an employer having decided

to resort to the payment of market forces supplements has to be gathered and

maintained. Proofs have to be relevant and proportionate to the additional sum granted

to the person concerned or to put it another way, these should be able to support the

grounds for which the entire supplement has been paid and not just being able to justify

part of it.

Evidence will include documentation of the recruitment process failure, eventually tried

also by means of external recruitment consultants, agencies and specialists, as well as

documentation of the findings of the regular assessment and review of the conditions

which have accounted for granting the supplement. Whether the exceptional

circumstances persist, the addition will continue to be paid; differently it has to

proportionally be reduced or completely removed according to the current conditions.

Finally, as a good rule of risk management, cases for market forces payment should be

prepared according to two main characteristics, more in particular these should be both

specific and measurable.

Reliability and validity of job evaluation

Job evaluation, irrespective of the approach used to design it, clearly is a demanding

process and its outcome may be prone to attract criticism and to be subject to a wide

range of drawbacks, giving sometimes rise to serious problems within the organization.

As contended by Armstrong and Cummins (2008), however, these undesirable effects

are usually caused by the bad execution of the scheme rather than by its inappropriate

design.

Evaluators should invariably carry out some forms of tests, checks and control of the

final version of the scheme they develop before its communication, introduction and

practical implementation. More specifically, these should always find the way to assess,

before considering definitively concluded their work, the reliability and validity of the

scheme they have designed.

233

Rating and ranking jobs

Jon evaluation reliability

Assessing the reliability of job evaluation results is everything but straightforward and

may require reward managers to have recourse to extra resources, provided that

employers are willing to make these available.

The most effective way to assess the outcome produced by job evaluation is to submit

the final rank emerged from the exercise to a panel formed by different evaluators who

have not originally been involved in the process. Whether these should associate the

same jobs with the same grade, on the basis of the same information, the system could

be deemed sorely reliable.

For demanding this process clearly is, it should not be neglected that on the other hand

it can enable:

• Evaluators to identify misleading and confused factor plans descriptions and

inappropriate, incomplete or incorrect job information;

• Employers to determine the expertise and capability of the evaluators in charge

of performing the exercise (Armstrong and Cummins, 2008). Albeit, in case of

diverging results, it will not be easy for an employer identify which of the two

teams has actually drawn the wrong conclusion.

Job evaluation validity

In general, a scheme can be deemed as valid when it is perceived as fair by employees

and can proof to be legally sound. Evaluators should hence demonstrate not only to be

capable to identify the right and most appropriate score to associate with each job, but

also to be able to consistently and appropriately pinpoint and outline the reasons and

arguments leading to the identification of a determined score rather than another (Arvey,

1986).

The methods mostly frequently used to assess the validity of the outcome produced by

job evaluation are called: criterion-related, content and construct validity.

The criterion-related approach is mainly aiming at determining whether it has been

attained a satisfactory level of consistency between internal relativities and the external

labour market data.

In the case of a scheme devised by means of an analytical approach, the content validity

methodology aims at determining whether the correct and relevant factors have actually

been identified, whereas in a non-analytical scheme, this method aims at identifying

whether the right benchmark jobs have been correctly identified and consistently graded.

The construct validity approach aims at ensuring the validity of the overall system by

means of determining if the final result of the process is actually coherent with the pre-

set aims and objectives. In order to assess a scheme validity by means of this approach,

a double evaluation process, based on two different methods, should be carried out

(Armstrong and Cummins, 2008).

234

Rating and ranking jobs

For different reasons, however, none of these approaches can actually be deemed as

completely fail-safe: the ascertained existence of a good degree of consistency between

internal hierarchies and external rates in actual fact does not insure employers against

the risk of equal pay claims. Similarly, having identified that right jobs factors does not

necessary entails that the final ranking will be correct, whereas carrying out two

different processes to establish validity would turn to be exceedingly demanding and

hardly realistic to be implemented in practice. These are basically the reasons why

evaluators prefer having recourse to an additional form of validity test called felt-fair test.

Felt-fair test

The concept of felt-fair pay was developed by Elliot Jaques (1961, 1964) during an

investigation on pay inequalities he was invited to carry out into the British firm Glacier,

on invitation of the organization’s trade unions officials. Jaques spent approximately a

year and a half asking to the factory’s employees what their opinion about pay

inequalities was. Unexpectedly, he found out that all of the organization employees

practically shared the same idea about the value and worthiness of the jobs performed

within the factory. Albeit he had realized that there was a widespread consent amongst

the employees about the value and worth of the different jobs, it was not immediately

obvious on which grounds this clear and shared perception was actually based. The

riddle was later suddenly solved thanks to three employees who told him that differences

in salary were in some ways associated with time: “floor operators were paid by the hour,

junior officers by the week, managers by the month and executives by the year” (Kleiner,

2001). Two years later, Jaques developed the concept of time span or “by when” concept

according to which the longer the length of time – time span – required to carry out the

duties typical of a role, the larger the amount of pay to be earned, perceived as fair –

hence felt fair – by individuals.

In addition to the time span of discretion, Jaques (1961) also considered crucially

important defining the potential capabilities of individuals, so that his model is essentially

based on matching together three variables: the time-span of discretion associated with

the work (W), the individual capacity for work or time-span of capacity (C) and pay (P).

The findings of Jaques research revealed that individuals develop an unconscious, but

surprisingly extensively shared perception and idea about jobs worthiness and the

related pay value and are consequently able to determine and assess, on the basis of

this perception, whether the salary they receive can be deemed as fair or otherwise.

Salary structures and pay levels should ultimately be designed and developed, therefore,

in a way which is perceived and felt as fair by individuals.

In order to avoid giving rise to individual perception of salary inequalities, the pay

received (PR) by an individual should fall within the pay norm (PN); that is PR=PN.

Whereas a differential should emerge and the level of pay received should be perceived

by individuals as lower vis-à-vis the pay norm, PR<PN, even though capabilities should

be perceived as matching capacity, C=W, this will lead to a perceived pay inequity,

namely C=W>P; which means that capacity and work performed are superior to pay.

235

Rating and ranking jobs

This clearly is the case of underpayment. Individuals will draw the same conclusions also

in the opposite case that is in the case the pay they receive is higher than that

considered as the pay norm: PR>PN and hence C=W<P; capacity and work are in this

case inferior to the salary received and inequity derives from overpayment.

Jaques (1961) suggested that inequality leading to the sensation of being underpaid

arises when individuals feel to be paid at least 5 per cent less than the pay norm and

that individuals seriously take actions to change job when this rate rises up to a 20 per

cent differential.

The felt-fair test idea was developed from the Jaques broader concept of felt-fair pay or,

as appropriately suggested by Armstrong and Cummins (2008), the concept has “been

hijacked” by job evaluators on the basis of the generic assumption that whether the

established hierarchy of jobs is perceived as fair it is hence fair. It is of paramount

importance, however, identify on the basis of the perceptions of whom a pay system has

to be felt and considered fair.

Risher (1989) canvassed the idea that “the only measure of system validity is

management’s assessment”, meaning by that that whether the established job hierarchy

is perceived by the business management as fitting the company’s structure,

compensation strategy and career map, it is by extension fair. This concept clearly

totally neglects the main tenet on the basis of which a reward management strategy

should be built up and developed: that is, aligning organizational objectives with

individual objectives. The circumstance that a pay system is perceived as fair by the

business management might mean little or nothing for employees, insofar as supporting

the validity of pay system exclusively on the basis of this could reveal to be particularly

detrimental to a business. As appropriately averred by Armstrong and Cummins (2008)

in fact not only individuals develop their own idea and perception about jobs value, but

they tend to refuse at best and to repel at worst systems leading to results sensibly

swerving from their perception.

Research on the practical application of the approach proposed by Jaques is rather

contradictory: findings of a study carried out by Hughes (2009) “provides limited support

for Jaques theory”; by contrast, an investigation carried out in Finland and Latvia by

Carraher and Carraher (2004) reached a different conclusion: it “appears that Jaques'

proposition does accurately predict different degrees of satisfaction with pay levels.”

Regardless of the methodology and approach adopted to test the validity, sustainability

and fairness of a salary structure, what can definitely be considered undisputable is that

it cannot be believed that this important form of judgment could exclusively rest with a

business management. A wider employee involvement definitely represents the ideal

solution; the worse comes to the worst, this activity has been carried out involving from

the very beginning trade unions officials and employee representatives. This can

effectively contribute to make the final output produced by the project team accepted by

the entire company’s staff.

236

Rating and ranking jobs

Planning a series of initiatives aiming at giving the chance to the components of the

evaluation panel to meet with employees in order to explain them the methodology

adopted to develop the scheme and devise the final rank can clearly definitely help too.

During the unfolding of such initiatives, where union officials and employee

representatives will clearly be invited to participate as members of the evaluation panel,

favouring a genuinely open two-way communication process is paramount. This

represents the most effective way to test, before the scheme is introduced and

implemented, the feelings it can produce, the way it is likely to be perceived by

employees at large and the reactions it may cause amongst individuals.

To develop and introduce fair pay systems which meet individuals fairness expectations,

employers also need to duly take into consideration the influence exerted by the external

environment, namely the labour market rates. These data can be collected by employers

in several ways, albeit gathering consistent and reliable data is not always as

straightforward as it may seem. Initiatives aiming at carrying out employees’ felt-fair

test can also definitely represent a very good opportunity for the project team to clarify

the divergences eventually existing between what employees consider pay norm and

what the project team has identified as external labour market norm for each assessed

role.

This process might also require additional time and resources, but it is definitely well-

worth the efforts. Not only can it enable the evaluation panel members to timely make

some useful and constructive amendments to the overall scheme, but it can also

contribute to ensure that the moment the scheme is introduced, it is not perceived as an

unexpected surprise by all of the individuals concerned. Whether employees have been

involved in the scheme development from the outset, these will have the chance to

eventually manifest their disagreement about the aspects these do not consider

appropriate so that some adjustments could eventually be timely and promptly

implemented on the basis of employees’ feedback. This approach practically ensures

companies to receive employees’ acceptance of the scheme before its official disclosure

and introduction.

237

References

Advisory, Conciliation and Arbitration Service, (2005), Job evaluation: an

introduction – Advisory booklet; London: ACAS.

Advisory,

Conciliation

and

Arbitration

Service, (2010), Job

evaluation:

considerations and risks – Advisory booklet; London: ACAS.

Agenda for Change Project Team, (2004), NHS Job Evaluation Handbook, 2nd Edition;

London: Department of Health.

Armstrong, M. , (2006), A handbook of Human Resource Management Practice, 10th

Edition; London: Kogan Page.

Armstrong, M., Cummins, A. , (2008), Valuing roles, how to establish relative worth;

London: Kogan Page.

Armstrong, M. , (2010), Armstrong’s handbook of reward management – Improving

performance through reward, 3rd Edition; London: Kogan Page.

Arvey, R. D. , (1986), Sex bias in job evaluation procedures, Personnel Psychology, No.

39, pages 315–335.

Bonsels, M. , (2009), Taking the best path to implementing a global level structure;

London: Mercer.

Carraher, S. M. and Carraher, S. C. , (2004), Felt fair pay of small to medium sized

enterprise (SME) owners in Finland and Latvia: an examination of Jaques equity

construct.

Charman, C. and Blackwell, G. , (2012), Grading 2.0: next-generation job levelling in

HR departments, HR Magazine.

Chartered Institute for Personnel and Development, (2004), Reward management

2004: A survey of policies and practice; London: CIPD.

Chartered Institute for Personnel and Development, (2007), Reward management:

Annual survey report 2007; London: CIPD.

Chartered Institute for Personnel and Development, (2010), Market pricing and

job evaluation – Factsheet; London: CIPD.

Chen, R. and Rosenstein, W. , (2009), Job alignment: as businesses rebound,

opportunities exist to make organizations run better and smarter; Stamford: McLagan –

Aon Consulting.

Edgell, R. , (2010), Job evaluation: what is it? , Managers-net.

Equality and Human Rights Commission, (2012), Market forces and pay, equal pay

in practice checklist 9. UK.

E-reward, (2007), Survey of job evaluation; Stockport: e-reward.

Hamel, M. C. , (2008), Compensation Guide: A Manual on Compensation Practice &

Theory; Toronto: Onestep.

Hay Group, (2005), Hay Job Evaluation – Foundations and applications; Philadelphia, PA:

Hay group.

Hay Group, (2007), Job analysis; Newcastle: Newcastle University.

Hay Group, (2013), Rohm & Haas: Job levelling – blending the best elements of job

evaluation and market pricing; Auckland: Hay Group.

Hay Group, (2007), Job levels profiles: descriptions of Birkbeck College grade levels.

HR-Exec, (2002), Job analysis and evaluation methods, HR-Exec.

238

Hughes, R. E. , (2009), Pay equity and satisfaction: the effects of underpayment and

aspirations with a review and implications for managers, The Coastal Business Journal,

Spring 2009, Volume 8, No. 9.

Income Data Services, (2003), Job evaluation, IDS Studies Plus 754; London: IDS.

Income Data Services, (2003), Job evaluation is alive and well despite market-drive