Basic Microeconomics by Professor R. Larry Reynolds, PhD - HTML preview

PLEASE NOTE: This is an HTML preview only and some elements such as links or page numbers may be incorrect.
Download the book in PDF, ePub, Kindle for a complete version.

V DETERMINANTS OF EP

Price Elasticity of demand is influenced by:

192

9.1.6 Elasticity

1. Availability of substitutes

Generally, the more substitutes that are available, the more elastic

the demand for a good. The demand for a class of goods (soft

drinks) is usually more inelastic than the demand for a specific

brand of the good (Pepsi or Coca-Cola). A Firm may try to

differentiate their product to make the demand relatively more

inelastic.

2. Proportion of item in budget

When the expenditures on a product are a relatively small portion

of a budget, the demand is relatively more elastic.

3. Time available to adapt

The longer that consumers or buyers have to make adjustments in

their behavior, the more elastic the demand is likely to be. The

absolute value of the short run price elasticity of demand for

gasoline would be smaller than the absolute value of the long

run price elasticity of demand. The longer time allows

consumers more opportunity to adjust to price changes.

VI INTERPRETATION OF EP

Some examples of price elasticities of demand reported in M

icroeconomics for

Today, [Tucker, p 123, South-Western College Publishing, 1999. Sources Archibald and Gillingham, Houthakker and

Taylor, Voith] are presented in Table IV.5. Note that the demand is relatively more

elastic for longer periods. Some goods, like movies, are inelastic in the short

run and elastic in the long run.

The coefficient or price elasticity can be used to estimate the percentage

change in the quantity that consumers are willing and able to buy given a

percentage change in the price. It is important to understand that this

measure does not apply to the equilibrium conditions in the market.

193

9.1.6 Elasticity

Table IV.5

Selected Price Elasticities

Item

Short Run EP

Long Run EP

Automobiles

-1.87

-2.24

Movies

-.087

-3.67

Medical Care

-.31

-.92

Gasoline

-.20

-.70

In Table IV.5 the short run EP for gasoline is -.2. This suggests that a 1%

increase in price will reduce the quantity demanded by .2%. A 10% decrease

in price would increase the quantity demanded by 2%. In the case of movies,

a 1% increase in the price would change the quantity demanded by 3.67% in

the long run.

(B) INCOME ELASTICITY OF DEMAND

The responsiveness of buyers to changes in their incomes is measured by

income elasticity. While EP measures a movement along a demand function as

the price changes, income elasticity (EM) measure a shift of the demand

function caused by a change in income.

Δ Q

Income elasticity (EM) is defined:

[ E

M

]

Δ Income

In Figure IV.A.12 the original demand function is represented as D. D1

represents a decrease in demand (at each price a smaller quantity is

purchased. When a larger quantity is purchased at each price, this will

represent an increase of demand to D2.

194

9.1.6 Elasticity

$ 10

(D) Q = 10 – 1P

Given the original

9

(D1) Q1 = 7 - 1P

(D2) Q2 = 13 – 1P

8

demand function (D),

rice P 7

consumers are willing and

6

A

B

C

able to purchase 5 units of

5

4

the good. If income

3

increased by 50% and

2

D1

D

D2

“caused” the demand to

1

shift to D

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Q/ut

2, where 8 units

Figure IV.A.12

are purchased at $5. This is

a 60% increase in demand. Income elasticity (EM) is calculated:

E

%ΔQ

+60

=

=

= +1 . 2

M

%ΔM

+50

In this case, an increase in income resulted in an increase in demand. A

decrease in income might decrease the demand (to D1). In this case income

%ΔQ

− 60

E

=

=

= +1 . 2

M

%ΔM

− 50

elasticity would be

When EM is positive, the good is called a normal good. If an

increase in income reduces demand (or a decrease in income increases

demand), EM will be negative and the good is categorized as an inferior good.

a. EM < 0 means the good is inferior, i.e. for an increase in income the

quantity purchased will decline or for a decrease in income the quantity

purchased will increase

195

9.1.6 Elasticity

b. 1 > ΕM> 0 means the good is a normal good, for an increase in income

the quantity purchased will increase but by a smaller percentage than the

percentage change in income.

c. For EM > 1 the good is considered a superior good.

CROSS ELASTICITY

Cross elasticity (EXY) is used as a measure of the relationship between two

goods. EXY is defined as:

% Δ Q

E

x

XY

% Δ P y

Consider two goods that are substitutes: butter and margarine. Cross

elasticity cam be used to measure the relationship between the price of butter

and the demand for margarine (EMargarine- butter) or the relationship between the

demand for butter and the price of margarine (Ebutter-margarine). The value of EXY is

not the same as or equal to EYX. In Figure IV.A.13 the concept of EXY is shown.

PM

PMH

DBH

PM

DM

DB

Q

Q

QBH

Q /ut

MH

M Q /ut

M

B

Panel

Panel

Figure

A

B

IV.A.13

196

9.1.6 Elasticity

In panel A, the demand for margarine (DM) is shown. At a price of PM, the

quantity demanded is QM. In Panel B, the demand for butter (DB) is shown. At

a price of PB, the quantity demanded is QB. If the price of margarine increased

to PMH (in Panel A), the quantity of margarine demanded decreases to QMH.

Since less margarine is purchased, the demand for butter increases to DBH (in

Panel B). Given the higher demand for butter the butter demanded (given the

higher price of margarine) has increased. A decrease in the price of margarine

would shift the demand for butter to the left (decrease). The coefficient of

cross elasticity would be positive.

In the case of complimentary goods, an increase (decrease) in the price of

tennis balls would reduce (increase) the demand for tennis rackets. The

coefficient of cross elasticity would be negative. If EXY is close to zero, that

would be evidence that the two goods were not related. If EXY were positive or

negative and significantly different from zero, it could be used as evidence that

the two goods are related. It is possible that EXY might be positive or negative

and the two goods are not related. The price of gasoline has gone up and the

demand for PC’s has also increased. This does not mean that gasoline and

PC’s are substitutes.

197

9.1.6 Elasticity

When Εxy > 0, [a positive number] this suggests that the two goods are substitutes

When Εxy < 0, [a negative number] this suggests that the two goods are

compliments

9.1.6.1 ELASTICITY AND BUYER RESPONSE

E lasticity is a convenient tool to describe how buyers respond to changes

in relevant variables. Price elasticity (EP) measures how buyers respond to

changes in the price of the good. It measures a movement along a demand

function. It is used to describe how much more of less the quantity demanded

is as the price falls or rises.

Income elasticity (EM) is a measure of how much the demand function

shifts as the income(s) of the buyer(s) changes. Cross elasticity (EXY)

measures how much changes in the price of a related good will shift the

demand function.

Elasticity can be calculated to estimate the relationship between any two

related variables.

198

10 Production and Cost

10 PRODUCTION AND COST

D ecisions about production require individual agents to make decisions

about the allocation and use of physical inputs. Objectives of agents,

technology, availability and quality of inputs determine the nature of these

decisions. Since the objectives are often pecuniary, it is often necessary to

relate the decisions about the physical units of inputs and outputs to the costs

of production.

If the prices of the inputs and the production relationships are known (or

understood), it is possible to calculate or estimate all the cost relationships for

each level of output. In practice however, the decision maker will probably

have partial information about some of the costs and will need to estimate

production relationships in order to make decisions about the relative amounts

of the different inputs to be used.

10.1 PRODUCTION

P roduction is the process of altering resources or inputs so they satisfy

more wants. Before goods can be distributed or sold, they must be produced.

Production, more specifically, the technology used in the production of a good

(or service) and the prices of the inputs determine the cost of production.

Within the market model, production and costs of production are reflected in

the supply function.

Production processes increase the ability of inputs (or resources) to satisfy

wants by:

• a change in physical characteristics

• a change in location

• a change in time

• a change in ownership

199

10.1 Production

At its most simplistic level, the economy is a social process that allocates

relatively scarce resources to satisfy relatively unlimited wants. To achieve this

objective, inputs or resources must be allocated to those uses that have the

greatest value. In a market setting, this is achieved by buyers (consumers)

and sellers (producers) interacting. Consumers or buyers wish to maximize

their utility or satisfaction given (or constrained by) their incomes, preferences

and the prices of the goods they may buy. The behavior of the buyers or

consumers is expressed in the demand function. The producers and/or sellers

have other objectives. Profits may be either an objective or constraint. As an

objective, a producer may seek to maximize profits or minimize cost per unit.

As a constraint the agent may desire to maximize “efficiency,” market share,

rate of growth or some other objective constrained by some “acceptable level

of profits. In the long run, a private producer will probably find it necessary to

produce an output that can be sold for more than it costs to produce. The

costs of production (Total Cost, TC) must be less than the revenues (Total

Revenue, TR).

Given a production relationship (Q = f (labor, land, capital, technology, …))

and the prices of the inputs, all the cost relationships can be calculated. Often,

in the decision making process, information embedded in cost data must be

interpreted to answer questions such as:

• “How many units of a good should be produced (to achieve the

objective)?”

• “How big should may plant be?’ or How many acres of land should I

plant in potatoes?”

Once the question of plant size is answered, there are questions,

• “How many units of each variable input should be used (to best achieve

the objective)?”

• “To what degree can one input be substituted for another in the

production process?”

200

10.1 Production

The question about plant size involves long run analysis. The questions

about the use of variable inputs relate to short-run analysis. In both cases, the

production relationships and prices of the inputs determine the cost functions

and the answers to the questions.

Often decision-makers rely on cost data to choose among production

alternatives. In order to use cost data as a “map” or guide to achieve

production and/or financial objectives, the data must be interpreted. The

ability to make decisions about the allocation and use of physical inputs to

produce physical units of output (Q or TP) requires an understanding of the

production and cost relationships.

The production relationships and prices of inputs determine costs. Here the

production relationships will be used to construct the cost functions. In the

decision making process, incomplete cost data is often used to make

production decisions. The theory of production and costs provides the road

map to the achievement of the objectives.

10.1.1 (1) PRODUCTION UNIT

I n the circular flow diagram found in most principles of economics texts,

production takes place in a “firm” or “business.” When considering the

production-cost relationships it is important to distinguish between firms and

plants. A plant is a physical unit of production. The plant is characterized by

physical units of inputs, such as land ® or capital (K). This includes acres of

land, deposits of minerals, buildings, machinery, roads, wells, and the like.

The firm is an organization that may or may not have physical facilities and

engage in production of economic goods. In some cases the firm may

manage a single plant. In other instances, a firm may have many plants or no

plant at all.

201

10.1.1 (1) Production Unit

The cost functions that are associated with a single plant are significantly

different from those that are associated with a firm. A single plant may

experience economies in one range of output and diseconomies of scale in

another. Alternatively, a firm may build a series of plants to achieve constant

or even increasing returns. General Motors Corp. is often used as an example

of an early firm that used decentralization to avoid rising costs per unit of

output in a single plant.

Diversification is another strategy to influence production and associated

costs. A firm or plant may produce several products. Alfred Marshall (one of

the early Neoclassical economists in the last decade of the 19th century)

considered the problem of “joint costs. “ A firm that produces two outputs

(beef and hides) will find it necessary to “allocate” costs to the outputs.

Unless specifically identified, the production and cost relationships will

represent a single plant with a single product.

10.1.2 (2) PRODUCTION FUNCTION

A production function is a model (usually mathematical) that relates

possible levels of physical outputs to various sets of inputs, eg.

Q = f (Labor,

Kapital, Land, technology, . . . ).

To simplify the world, we will use two inputs Labor (L) and Kapital (K) so,

Q = f (L, K, technology, ...).

Here we will use a Cobb-Douglas production function that usually takes the

form: Q = ALaKb. In this simplified version, each production function or

process is limited to increasing, constant or decreasing returns to scale over

the range of production. In more complex production processes, “economies

of scale” (increasing returns) may initially occur. As the plant becomes larger

(a larger fixed input in each successive short-run period), constant returns

202

10.1.2 (2) Production Function

may be expected. Eventually, decreasing returns or “diseconomies of scale”

may be expected when the plant size (fixed input) becomes “too large.” This

more complex production function is characterized by a long run average cost

(cost per unit of output) that at first declines (increasing returns), then is

horizontal (constant returns) and then rises (decreasing returns).

10.1.3 (3) TIME AND PRODUCTION

A s the period of time is changed, producers have more opportunities to

alter inputs and technology. Generally, four time periods are used in the

analysis of production:

market period” -

A period of time in which the producer cannot change any inputs nor

technology can be altered. Even output (Q) is fixed.

Short-run”-

A period in which technology is constant, at least one input is fixed

and at least one input is variable.

Long-run” -

A period in which all inputs are variable but technology is constant.

The very Long-run” -

During the very long-run, all inputs and technology change.

Most analysis in accounting, finance and economics is either long run or

short-run.

203

10.1.4 (4) Production in the Short-Run

10.1.4 (4) PRODUCTION IN THE SHORT-RUN

I n the short-run, at least one input is fixed and technology is unchanged

during the period. The fixed input(s) may be used to refer to the “size of a

plant.” Here K is used to represent capital as the fixed input. Depending on the

production process, other inputs might be fixed. For heuristic purposes, we will

vary one input. As the variable input is altered, the output (Q) changes. The

relationship between the variable input (here L is used for “labor”) and the

output (Q) can be viewed from several perspectives.

The short-run production function will take the form

Q = f (L), K and technology are fixed or held constant

A change in any of the fixed inputs or technology will alter the short-run

production function.

Q

Or

In the short run, the TP

B

relationship between the

TP

physical inputs and output can

be describes from several

A

perspectives. The relationship

can be described as the total

product, the output per unit of

input (the average product, AP)

O

L

Input (L)

A

LB

or the change in output that is

Figure V.1

attributable to a change in the

variable input (the marginal product, MP).

204

10.1.4 (4) Production in the Short-Run

Total product (TP or Q) is the total output. Q or TP = f(L) given a fixed

size of plant and technology.

Average product (APL) is the output per unit of input. AP = TP/L (in this

case the output per worker). APL is the average product of labor.

AP

output

TP

Q

=

=

=

L

Input

L

L

Marginal Product (MPL) is the change in output “caused” by a change in

the variable input (L),

ΔT P

ΔQ

MP =

=

L

ΔL

ΔL

(A) TOTAL AND MARGINAL PRODUCT

Over the range of inputs there are four possible relationships between Q and L

(1) TP or Q can increase at an increasing rate. MP will increase, (In Figure V.1

this range is from O to LA.)

(2) TP may pass through an inflection point, in which case MP will be a

maximum. (In Figure V.1, this is point A at LA amount of input.) TP or Q may

increase at a constant rate over some range of output. In this case, MP will

remain constant in this range.

(3) TP might increase at a decreasing rate. This will cause MP to fall. This is

referred to as “diminishing MP.” In Figure V.1, this is shown in the range from

LA to LB.

(4) If “too many” units of the variable input are added to the fixed input, TP

can decrease, in which case MP will be negative. Any addition of L beyond LB

will reduce output: the MP of the input will be negative. It would be foolish to

continue adding an input (even if it were “free”) when the MP is negative.

The relationship between the total product (TP) and the marginal product (MP)

can be shown. In Figure V.2, note that the inflection point in the TP function is

at the same level of input (LA) as the maximum of the MP. It is also important

205

10.1.4 (4) Production in the Short-Run

to understand that the maximum of the TP occurs when the MP of the input is

zero at LB.