Basic Microeconomics by Professor R. Larry Reynolds, PhD - HTML preview

PLEASE NOTE: This is an HTML preview only and some elements such as links or page numbers may be incorrect.
Download the book in PDF, ePub, Kindle for a complete version.

Figure

QX

to answer that question.

to answer that question.

I.A.6

Allocative or economic

efficiency includes the values or relative prices of outputs and inputs. The

benefit or value of a choice is represented by the product of the price and

quantity of each good or output (value of output = PxQx +PyQy + . . . +PnQn).

The value of the inputs or cost is represented by the product of the prices and

quantities of the inputs (cost = PLL + PKK + …+ PiQi). Allocative efficiency is

229

11.2 Criteria to evaluate alternatives

attained when we maximize the value of the outputs relative to the value of

the inputs. The cost is minimized for a given output or output is maximized for

a given cost. The economically efficient solution must lie on the production

possibilities function.

Pareto efficiency is the condition where there are no alternatives that will

increase the welfare (utility) of one person without reducing the welfare

(utility) of any other person(s). Once an output combination on the production

possibility function is attained, that output combination is Pareto Optimal.

The output combination at point H is not Pareto Optimal.

The output combination at point H is not Pareto Optimal.

Irrespective of individual preferences a move from point

Q A

Irrespective of individual preferences a move from point

Y

B

H to output combinations at point B or D (or any where

H to output combinations at point B or D (or any where

C

in the area HDB represent “Pareto Improvements.”

in the area HDB represent “Pareto Improvements.”

Each alternative in the area HDB is “Pareto Superior” to

Each alternative in the area HDB is “Pareto Superior” to

the alternative represent by point H.

D

the alternative represent by point H.

If the current output combination were at point E, it

If the current output combination were at point E, it

H

would be Pareto Optimal even if it were not he highest

would be Pareto Optimal even if it were not he highest

valued output. Any increase in good Y (or X) would

E

valued output. Any increase in good Y (or X) would

require a decrease in good X (or Y). The individuals who

require a decrease in good X (or Y). The individuals who

prefer X (or Y) to Y (or X) would be “worse off” (their

prefer X (or Y) to Y (or X) would be “worse off” (their

utility or welfare is lower).

F

utility or welfare is lower).

If the output is currently at point H, the area HDB is

If the output is currently at point H, the area HDB is

Figure

QX

called “Pareto Safe.”

called “Pareto Safe.”

I.A.6

Pareto efficiency is a

restrictive criteria and tends to promote the status quo. Most choices involve

marginal benefits and marginal costs that change the welfare or utility of more

than one individual. The Pareto efficiency criterion fails to justify choices that

result in the highest valued use of resources (economic efficiency). To remedy

this problem the criterion of Pareto Potential is used. Pareto Potential

justifies the choice of an alternative so long as the “winners” (individuals

whose utility increased) can hypothetically compensate the “losers”

(individuals whose utility decreased) and still be better off. This is the

foundation of criteria such as Benefit/cost analysis, rate of return on

230

11.2 Criteria to evaluate alternatives

investment and internal rates of return. The problem with Pareto Potential is

that it introduces the question of equity. Consider the problem of breaching

dam is the Pacific Northwest. There are winners and losers. Environmentalists,

individuals who benefit from anadromous fish and agents who earn income

from tourists are some of the winners. Electricity generators and farmers are

examples of losers. Even if the marginal benefits of breaching the dam

exceeded the marginal costs, there is no mechanism to insure the winners

would compensate the losers. There is necessarily a judgment about the

morality of the dams and the imposition of costs and benefits of various

groups of individuals. This example also illustrates the issue that the status

quo tends to be supported by the Pareto Optimality criterion. Building the

dams imposed costs and conferred benefits on different groups of people just

as breaching the dams will. As societies and individuals change their

preferences, technology and environments change and alter the objectives

and optimal use of scarce resources. In an ideal world, informed individuals

engaged in voluntary exchanges will result in transfers of property rights that

are Pareto improvements and lead to economic efficiency.

(2)Equity is a judgment about the rightness or wrongness of the objective.

Earlier, deontological and consequentialist ethics were discussed. Any

objective can be ethical or unethical based on the type of ethical system used.

Remember that microeconomics relies primarily on a consequential ethic called

“Utilitarianism” and is directly related to the concept of Pareto Potential. If the

benefits exceed the costs of an action, the consequence is an increase in

utility. This does not mean that deontological ethics (based on duty) are not

necessary for a reasonably functioning society. It is important to consider the

morality of our objectives and the sacrifices that must be made to achieve

them.

231

11.2.1 Marginal Analysis

11.2.1 MARGINAL ANALYSIS

R

F

T he Marginalist Revolution in economics

during the last half of the 19th century provided

F’

economists with a useful tool to find maximums

and minimums given functional relationships

R’ between variables. Basically, this Marginalist

Revolution was the application of calculus to economic analysis. One of the

purposes of economics is to maximize of minimize a given variable by making

choices. Choices are always made at the margin. A saying attributed to some

anonymous Chinese philosopher is “The longest journey begins with the first

step.” This is used here to point out that every decision is a change from an

initial state. In production, the manager must understand that a change in an

input such as labor “causes” a change in output. A consumer must understand

that a change in quantity consumed alters the level of utility. A seller must

understand that a change in price alters the quantity sold and the total

revenue. Marginal analysis is the analysis of rates of changes in variables.

Every time the word “marginal” is used in economics it is related to a change

in a dependent variable “caused” by a change in an independent variable. The

rate of change can be interpreted as the slope of a line. The slope of a line is

often defined as “rise over run. ” The rise is usually the change in the

dependent variable while the run is the change in the independent variable.

For example, the cost of producing more of one good, given full employment,

requires a sacrifice of some other good. This was demonstrated in a

Production Possibilities model. The slope of the PPF is called the “Marginal Rate

of Transformation” (MRT). This is shown in Figure VI.1. The PPF function

shows all combinations of Yawls (Y) and Xebecs (X) that can be produced

given inputs and technology.

232

11.2.1 Marginal Analysis

At point B, an increase in X (∆ X=15, the run) requires a

sacrifice of 15 units of Y (∆ Y=-15) This tradeoff is called

)

A

50

A

B

45

the Marginal Rate of Transformation (MRT) and is

ls (Y

A

aw

illustrated by the line RR’. When the MRT (or slope) is

Y

C

30

A

calculated by subtracting values (∆ ), the marginal value is

the slope of an arc between the points.

D

19

A

When the slope is calculated by a derivative, the value of ∆ X

approaches 0, so the marginal value is represented by the

E

slope of a tangent. In this example, it the slope of FF’ at

A

200

35

38 40

point B.

Xebecs (X)

Figure VI.1

If the output were at X = 20, Y = 45 (shown as point B in Figure VI.1), an

increase in Xebecs would require a decrease in the output of Y. The increase in

X from 20 to 35 is 15 units of X. This is labeled as ∆X = 15 (35-20=15) and is

the “run.” The change in Y (∆Y) is -15 (30-45= -15) and is called the “rise.”

The line RR’ represents the change in Y (∆Y) caused by the change in X (∆X).

rise

ΔY

Slope of RR' =

=

, or the change in Y caused by a change in X

run

ΔX

The slope of RR’ is

-15 ( rise ) =−1

15 ( run )

Calculus lets the change in X approach 0. When the change in X

approaches 0, the change in Y is shown by the line FF’ which is tangent to the

PPF at point B. In principles of economics calculus is not normally required so

the term marginal is calculated by differences and is represented by the slope

of a straight line. When a function is nonlinear, the slope between two points

is the slope of an arc.

233

11.2.1 Marginal Analysis

It is crucial to remember that the marginal value (cost, benefit, etc) is the

value associated with a specific choice.

(1) marginal benefit (MB) is the change in total benefits associated with a

choice. For an individual MB might be MU for a firm it may be MR

(2) marginal cost (MC) is the change in total cost (or variable cost since

fixed costs don’t change) caused by a change in and activity, usually

production.

(3) marginal decision rule You should engage in any activity so long as the

MB > MC, the optimal level of activity is where MB = MC, when MC>MB you

should not undertake the activity. There is a variation of this rule called the

equimarginal rule.

The marginal decision rule can be illustrated by the decision to gather wild

blackberries (good X). The cost of travel to the blackberry patch is treated

here as a sunk (fixed) cost, we are already at the patch. How many berries

shall we pick? The answer depends on our analysis of the benefits and costs of

each unit of berries we pick. Generally, the marginal benefits of berries will

tend to decrease primarily because of diminishing marginal utility. The

marginal benefit (MB) of each unit of berries is shown in Figure VI.2. Typically

we will gather the berries that are easiest to pick first. These are the berries

MB and MC

MC

B

E

P= MB= MC

MB

C

R

0

73

Berries/ut

234

Figure VI.2

11.2.1 Marginal Analysis

that are approximately waist level and on the outside of the bushes. As we

pick more berries we have to reach further up or down and into the bushes

where there are thorns. The marginal cost (MC) of berries rises. The MC of

each unit of berries is also shown in Figure VI.2. The MB function decreases as

more berries are obtained. The area under the MB function up to the quantity

obtained represents the total benefits (TB). In Figure VI.2 when 73 units are

picked, TB is the area 0REB. The MC rises as berries become more difficult to

pick. MC represents the marginal cost of each unit. The total costs (TC) is the

area under the MC function. When 73 units of berries are picked, the TC will

be represented by the area 0REC (the area in blue). The first units of berries

are picked because the marginal benefit of each unit (MB) is greater than the

marginal cost (MC). There is a net benefit obtained from each unit. Seventy-

three units of berries are picked because the MB of the first 73 units is greater

than the MC of those units. The TB is 0REB: the TC is 0REC. The net benefit is

the area CEB (in yellow). Net benefits are maximized when MB = MC.

This rule has several applications.

Where MR = MC, profits are maximized

Where MB = P (cost), utility is maximized

This rule was first clearly stated by the French engineer/economist, Jules

Dupuit in the 1830’s.

235

11.2.2 Market Exchange and Efficiency

11.2.2 MARKET EXCHANGE AND EFFICIENCY

T he ideal market has two important characteristics:

Individuals voluntarily contract among themselves. There is no coercion and each

is informed of their preferences (objectives) and alternatives. They make informed

judgments about the outcomes of their choices.

The individuals exchange goods that are characterized by nonattenuated property

rights. Nonattenuated property rights are exclusive, enforceable and transferable. The

benefits and cost associated with the production or consumption of any good falls only

on the agents engaged in the contract or transaction.

Under these conditions, from a utilitarian perspective, no one would

rationally engage in a voluntary exchange if it made them worse off.

Therefore, any voluntary exchange must lead to Pareto superior results.

Individual agents know their preferences (objectives) and react to any

changes by altering their choices. The idealized market results in individuals

who constantly reappraise their objectives and alternatives and alter choices

to maximize their welfare. Since exchanges are perceived to be voluntary, no

individual would choose to make themselves worse off. Voluntary markets of

goods with nonattenuated property rights are consistent with the Utilitarian

Ethic and Pareto Efficiency.

236

11.2.3 Prices as Information

MB and MC

MC

B

E

P= MB= MC

MB

C

R

0

73

Berries/ut

Figure VI.2

11.2.3 PRICES AS INFORMATION

The function of the market is to coordinate the preferences and behavior of

the buyers and sellers. There are two important elements that are necessary if

markets are to perform this task of coordination. First, buyers and sellers must

have information. Prices, or more precisely relative prices perform this task.

Secondly, buyers and sellers must have an incentive to respond to the

information contained in prices.

Using Figure VI.2 again, the role of prices can be shown. The MB function

represents the buyers’ evaluations of their marginal benefits. As the quantity

of berries increases, the marginal value goes down, The MB function is

negatively sloped and resembles a demand function. It is not a demand

function because it does not include the ability to buy the goods. It only

measures the buyers’ evaluation of marginal benefits. Notice the MB of the

73rd unit to the buyers is P. Similarly, the MC function represents the

opportunity cost or producing each unit. The MC of producing the 73rd unit is

also P. For all unit of berries, up to and including, the 73rd unit, the MB is

greater than the MC. We could restate this: the marginal benefit from each of

237

11.2.3 Prices as Information

the first 73 units is greater than its opportunity cost. The value (MB) that

buyers have for each of the first 73 units is greater than the market price of P.

The sellers sacrifice an opportunity cost of less than P on each of the first 73

units. The price of P represents the marginal value (MB) of the last unit

exchanged to the buyers. P also represents the marginal value (MC) of the last

unit exchanged to the sellers. A price of P provides information about both the

buyers and sellers evaluations. Since MB = MC produces maximum net

benefit, the ideal is where the price reflects MB and MC, MB = P = MC.

So long as the price is less than the MB of the buyers, additional units will

be purchased. Once the P > MB buyers cease to purchase the good.

When the P > MC, sellers will produce and offer units for sale. Once the P <

MC, the sellers will cease production.

238

12 Pure Competition

12 PURE COMPETITION

P urely competitive markets are used as the benchmark to evaluate

market performance. It is generally believed that market structure influences

the behavior and performance of agents within the market. Structure

influences conduct which, in turn affects performance.

12.1 MARKET STRUCTURE

N eoclassical microeconomics is an explanation of the behavior of

individuals, firms, and organizations within a market context. Their behavior is

thought to be a function of their objectives and the constraints that exist

because of technology, quantity/quality of inputs and market structure. Market

structures can be characterized by sellers or buyers or both. Most economics

texts classify markets by seller. Generally, they identify 4 basic types of

markets: (1) pure (or perfect) competition, (2) monopolistic (or imperfect)

competition, (3) oligopolistic competition, and (4) monopoly. Pure competition

is believed to produce ideal results in the allocation of resources. Monopoly is

usually depicted as having less than optimal outcomes. The basic market

structures based on sellers is shown in Figure VII.1

239

12.1 Market Structure

Figure VII.1

Ideal outcomes

Deviate from Ideal

Market Structure

Pure

Imperfect or

Competition

Monopolistic

Oligopoly

Monopoly

1. Many sellers

Competition

1. Few sellers

1. one seller

2. homogeneous

1. Many sellers

(interdependence)

2. no close

2. identical or

substitutes

products

2. differentiated

products

differentiated

3 complete BTE

3. relative ease of

3. relative ease of

product

entry

entry

3. BTE

Pure competition and Monopoly are at each end of the spectrum of

markets. In fact, probably neither occur in market economies. Pure

competition and monopoly are the boundaries and the “real world” (wherever

that is) lies somewhere between the two extremes. Pure competition provides

the benchmark that can be use to evaluate markets. The physician who

attends you knows that 98.6o is a benchmark. Your temperature may not be

precisely 98.6o, but if it deviates significantly, that deviation suggests

problems. It might be in your best interests to know what the “normal”

temperature is and the cause of the deviation from “normal.”

240

12.1.1 Characteristics of Pure Competition

12.1.1 CHARACTERISTICS OF PURE COMPETITION

T he idealized purely competitive market insures that no buyer or seller

has any market power or ability to influence the price. The sellers in a purely

competitive market are price takers. The market sets the price and each

seller reacts to that price by altering the variable input and output in the short

run. In the long rung they can alter the scale of plant (size of the fixed input in

each short run period). The conditions that ensure no seller has any market

pose are:

Large number of sellers (and buyers), no one of which can influence the

market.

• Homogeneous output, buyers see goods as perfect substitutes.

• Relatively “free” entry and exit to and from the market.

S ellers cannot charge a price above the market price because sellers see all

other goods in the market as perfect substitutes. They can buy those goods at

the market price.

12.2 THE FIRM IN PURE COMPETITION

A purely competitive market is characterized by a large number of

relatively small firms. No single firm can influence the market price and are

considered price takers. In Figure VII.2 graphs representing a purely

competitive market and one firm are shown.

Panel A.VII.2 represents the market. DM and SM represent the market

demand and supply functions. If the market is in equilibrium the equilibrium

price and quantities are PEM and QEM respectively. Notice that the quantity

measured along the Q-axis in Panel A represent large quantities.

241

12.2 The Firm in Pure Competition

SM

rice, $

rice, $

P

P

EM

D

P

f

EM