Rhetoric and Practice of Reward Management by Rosario Longo - HTML preview

PLEASE NOTE: This is an HTML preview only and some elements such as links or page numbers may be incorrect.
Download the book in PDF, ePub, Kindle for a complete version.

large amounts of money, but also to do it quickly. Once again, former Société Générale

trader Jérôme Kerviel is a remarkable example of what a single person could be able to

do, but also an amazing example of how true is that at superior level nobody was able to

understand and foreseen the hazard of the transactions traders were carrying out on the

banks’ behalf and of how risk was not object of appropriate and constant control within

the bank.

381

Making the case for and against variable pay

As suggested by the Independent Commission on Banking established in the UK,

reported profits on the basis of which traders were paid were neither risk- nor time-

adjusted. The latter reference has to be associated with the lack of consistency of the

overall bonus system with the same banks’ long-term interest. Bonuses were paid

immediately, whereas benefits for the banks would have been eventually reaped in the

future. As suggested by Stiglitz (2011), the system was rather designed to “encourage

excessive-risk taking” or even gambling.

Could have HR and reward specialists helped to avoid the impending disaster caused by

excessive risk-taking and bonus payments? Either we consider bonuses as a contributor

factor to the financial disaster or as a “symptom rather than a cause” (Cotton, 2011), we

can agree with Williams (2011) that it is very likely that HR could have actually done

little or nothing to avoid the catastrophe. Before the issue emerged publicly, whatever

HR’s attempt to persuade the banks board to change their bonus payment system would

have certainly been tantamount to pure madness. When in 2008 the Royal Bank of

Scotland (RBS) changed its bonus system, shifting from cash bonuses to fully deferred

bonuses, it underwent a brain drain phenomenon leading attrition to double.

Smedley (2011) suggests that the real problem was that nobody was considering the

risks associated with “high-value reward for short-term risk-taking”, the system failure

was hence essentially linked to the way the overall mechanism worked and with the way

banks were used to get massive profits.

Additionally, according to Wright (2011), the major risk was not that much associated

with paying bonuses for transactions made in the short run, but rather with the

circumstance that bonuses were paid before the final outcome of transactions were even

known. Banks should have better used deferred bonuses approaches, but did not

because they would have otherwise risked immediately losing their best talents. It would

be just like proposing to Arsenal, Real Madrid or Inter Milan soccer players a £200,000

salary a year, professional footballers would definitely leave their teams lured by the

staggering pay offered by Barcelona, Manchester City and Milan or by other football

clubs.

The anonymous former senior HR professional cited above related that, as long as

traders were enabling the bank to collect large sums of money, they could do whatever

they wanted. Nobody, for instance, dared to fire a manager who had received several

final written warnings on his personal record given the fact that this accounted for the 10

per cent of the bank profit.

After the financial crisis burst, the way banks and financial institutions were paying

bonuses to their investment specialists emerged and after everybody was acquainted

with the issue, as expectable, regulators come to play.

In the UK, the Companies Act 2006 already included specific rules concerning the

disclosure of the banks and financial institutions boardrooms members’ compensations,

but traders and senior executives’ pays were not included in the provisions.

382

Making the case for and against variable pay

Subsequently, the European Capital Requirement Directive III (CRD III) was

promulgated and the UK Financial Services Authority (FSA) Remuneration Code was

amended introducing some significant restraints.

More in particular, the FSA Remuneration Code introduced regulations prescribing that:

no less than half the amount of the agreed bonuses could be paid in the organization’s

shares or in other equivalent non-cash means; no less than 40 per cent of variable pay

for “code staff” (namely, senior managers, risk takers, staff in charge of control

functions and other staff who receive a remuneration package at senior management

level) had to be paid over a period of at least three years; this percentage (still of

variable pay or incentives) had to be raised to 60 per cent for individuals receiving an

annual pay of more than £500,000. Additionally, according to the amended provisions,

financial firms could no longer offer guaranteed or retention bonuses of more than one

year.

The EU CRD III directive went even further afield ruling that, in their annual report,

organizations needed to:

Provide information about the way remunerations were decided and reward

systems designed;

Explain the link existing between pay and performance;

Explain factors and underlying principles for resorting to variable pay;

Disclose comprehensive details about senior managers and risk-takers

remuneration.

In order to avoid the risks associated with traders’ activity, banks are now reinforcing

their risk control systems and developing KPIs enabling them to assess individual

performance in a systematic way, taking also into account risk exposure.

Just a very few years ago, whether proposed by the HR function, such measures would

have been tantamount to HR bureaucracy and definitely rejected by the banks’ boards

(Williams, 2011).

Albeit it would have been virtually impossible to do it in the past, because of the way the

overall system was working, banks are now turning towards more traditional

performance management processes and developing engagement strategies (Wright,

2011).

The final and decisive coup de grace to the banking reward system, however, has been

actually inflicted by the European Parliament approbation of the EU CRD IV, introducing,

amongst the other measures, a cap on bankers’ bonuses. More specifically, the new

regulation provides for all of the banks operating in the European Union territory to

comply with a 1 to 1 (1:1) ratio of base to variable pay of the reward packages agreed

and paid to their staff. This ratio can actually be increased to 1 to 2 (1:2), but only with

the approval of at least 66 per cent of the shareholders, whether these represent the

quorum of 50 per cent of the total institution’ shares; differently, the 75 per cent of the

votes is required.

383

Making the case for and against variable pay

In the light of the new legislation and of its development, reward specialists are now

clearly acquiring a major role within the banking and financial institutions. Their role,

however, is really going to be everything but straightforward, they have in fact to design,

develop and implement practices enabling their organizations to attract and retain

individuals who are used to earn large amounts of money, and even quickly, not

exclusively relying on financial reward. It is quite improbable that bankers will gladly

accept a cafeteria benefit scheme, unless this would offer them the option to choose

between, for instance, a Ferrari, diamonds and some other luxury items. Let alone it is

expectable that these individuals would get excited about the introduction of a voluntary

benefit scheme. It is therefore most likely that cash is still destined to remain the most

appealing component of banks total reward packages. The legal framework development

is thus likely to cause a turn of tide in the financial sector reward practices; in order to

secure to investment experts the reward packages these are used to and readdress and

counterbalance the effects of the new legislation, employers could decide to increase the

fixed component of financial reward (Longo, 2011b).

Increasing basic salaries, however, would clearly impact the firm fixed costs, which will

make it even harder for organizations to eventually face future downturn periods.

Keeping higher the level of fixed pay would in fact mean that in case of economic

recession, in order to reduce costs, banks will have no other option but to make people

redundant (Longo, 2011b). Yet, once the fixed component of pay has been mutually

agreed between the employer and the financial professional, this will need to be paid by

the institution regardless of the individual performance. In the light of the peculiarity of

the profession this does not clearly represent an ideal solution for the financial sector

employers. It would be in actual fact like paying a sales professional a higher percentage

of base pay irrespective of the annual total volume of sales s/he is capable of yielding.

Indeed, in the banking sector it is even worse in that not only at the end of a year an

investment specialist can contribute nothing to the bank, but this can also even cause a

disaster. The case of Mr. Kerviel taught us a lesson also in this sense; putting aside the

causes behind it, is it unquestionable that he originated a huge loss to the bank. What if,

rather than having being paid approximately €100,000 a year, he would have received

€400,000 or €500,000 a year? The bank would have practically suffered even more. It

should be considered that individuals filling these positions can generate losses not

necessarily worth to attract the media interest and that things can go objectively wrong

when performing that type of activity. Whether these losses would be caused by several

individuals at the same time the consequences could affect and cause remarkable

prejudice to the overall financial institution operations, whereas these individuals would

continue to receive staggering salaries.

Balancing overall reward packages towards variable pay does not potentially produce the

same threat; banks could also pay their staff large sums of money, but only when

businesses are performing sorely well. Risks would even be reduced to zero whether

banks would pay bonuses only after having ascertained to actually having cashed in

thanks to their professionals’ activities.

384

Making the case for and against variable pay

In terms of reward and of how employers balance the ratio between fixed and variable

pay, we have witnessed to two completely different scenarios. Banking and financial

services employers have traditionally offered bankers reward packages markedly and

predominantly variable-oriented, whereas private and public sectors employers have

offered to their staff reward packages mostly fixed-oriented or, if the worst comes to the

worst, balanced.

Whilst the aftermath of the financial crisis and the following reviewed legislation has

more recently pushed banks to readdress their views about the composition of the

reward packages they offer, or rather, of the ratio of fixed pay vis-à-vis variable pay, the

other industries are doing and planning to do exactly the opposite. In general, private

sector employers, contrary to banks, are the more and more incline to contain basic

salary and to contribute more generous variable components of financial reward to their

staff according to their actual results. Used in such a way, bonuses could actually be

considered fairer than they might seem.

This is, for instance, what emerged from the findings of an investigation carried out by

Farmer (2010). The study, covering the period from 2003 to 2007, when the new

regulation imposing big companies to disclose their top bosses remunerations had been

introduced, includes salaries of 200 UK’s big organizations such as Tesco, British Airlines,

GSK, BT and WH Smith. Findings of this study suggested that only 38 per cent of CEOs

bonuses were received automatically that is without any correlation between the

additional component of pay they received and their or their organization actual

performance. In the remaining 62 per cent of the investigated cases, CEOs received

higher financial reward packages if, and only if, they had done a good job enabling

businesses to increase their profits or their company’s share price. Conversely, that is, in

case of negative performance of their organizations, CEOs undergone a salary reduction

(Tobin, 2010).

Farmer’s investigation shows that when making decisions about a financial reward

package what matters the most is to separately consider its different components, rather

than regard the overall compensation package. The study also revealed that private

sector executives’ salary packages are better designed (and, indeed, a step forward)

compared to traders and banks senior managers’ salaries in that during the period from

2003 to 2007 these salaries have the more and more aimed at rewarding long-term

achievements rather than short-term success.

Over the period investigated, the proportion of variable reward linked to long-term

incentives increased from 22 per cent to 28 per cent. Additionally, CEOs who wanted to

receive the highest level of variable pay had to show their shareholders that they really

deserved it achieving better results than their industry competitors (Tobin, 2010).

The study carried out by Farmer could not be extended to banks for a whole range of

reasons, amongst them the fact that, as claimed by Farmer himself, a thorough and

reliable investigation of banks pay would have required access to senior bankers’ pay in

addition to that of boards members. Farmer also highlighted the circumstance that at the

385

Making the case for and against variable pay

time bankers bonuses were “used synonymously" with executive pay. More importantly,

as discussed earlier, many bankers earn remarkably more than executives as a matter of

course.

Farmer admits that the way bonuses are managed in banks is typical of the banking and

financial sector only and that the same approach is not habitually used in any other

industry.

Automatic bonuses

According to a relatively recent survey carried out by Towers Watson (2013), the

number of employers offering to their staff bonus programmes is constantly growing

compared to the figure emerged from similar investigations carried out in the early and

mid-2000s. Findings of the study also revealed that the number of organizations

extending staff eligibility to bonus schemes is constantly increasing. This can, in general,

be perceived as a clear indicator of how employers are determined to link pay to

performance and can thus be appreciated. What, in contrast, appears to be much less

positive, or rather, completely negative is the use private sector employers are making

of bonuses. According to the findings of the Towers Watson investigation in fact

employers would be the more and more executing automatic bonus schemes practices

by means of which individuals receive the pre-agreed component of variable pay

regardless of their, or of their organization, performance.

Albeit private sector employees’ proportion of variable pay to fixed pay is not

comparable to that of bankers, whether confirmed, this trend should not be considered

positively. It is obviously unlikely to generate any international financial crisis, but

drawbacks for organizations can potentially be remarkable. Inasmuch as identifying and

developing brand new, effectual approaches enabling employers to really motivate their

staff becomes the harder and harder, completely losing the support of reward to this

extent can seriously risk completely weakening and jeopardizing the effectiveness of any

reward strategy.

In many cases managers may find it objectively difficult to assess and measure their

direct reports performance, but the diffusion of automatic bonuses is not really the

correct solution; on the contrary, this could contribute to magnify the issue. Whether

measuring performance should reveal to be particularly tough and tricky, especially if the

business has not provided managers the tools and training necessary for these to

properly carry out this task, managers could try to base their assessment on individual

behaviour, gained competencies and capabilities and other similar, albeit judgmental,

elements, rather than automatically pay bonuses.

Automatic bonus practices may help employers to attract individuals from the external

environment, but whether strongly attracted by this bonus payment mechanism it can

hardly be believed that these would be hard workers, hi-flyers or real talents.

Whether automatic bonuses should spread amongst private sector employers, it is very

likely that bonuses will gain back the media interest anytime soon, whereas firms

fostering these practices might be prompted to face reputational risks.

386

Making the case for and against variable pay

The

impact

of

the

European

financial

sector

regulation

development

The approbation of the EU CRD IV Directive, which had been expressly developed with

the intent of preventing the risk of other international financial crises, introducing

specific rules about the bonus-to-salary ratio, shows that, at least at the European

political level, a clear relationship between bankers’ bonuses and the past international

financial crisis has been identified.

The effects and implications of the Capital Requirements Directive are actually twofold,

on the one hand it imposes clear constraints to the banks autonomy to determine the

bonus-to-salary ratio of employees receiving an income above a pre-set threshold;

whereas on the other hand it introduces more stringent and severe provisions aiming at

increasing banks’ reserves whilst ensuring their prompt availability, or rather, liquidity.

With particular reference to the bonus-to-salary ratio, the bonus cap has been

introduced as regards the reward packages received by individuals deemed as “material

risk takers.” According to the new regulation an individual who do not receive a reward

package exceeding €750,000 and who do not manage any risks for the institution this

work with can be exempted from the bonus cap limitation. Individuals receiving reward

packages between €750,000 and €1,000,000 can be exempted from the limitation

whether their exclusion is approved by the national regulator, in the UK the Prudential

Regulation Authority. For individuals receiving over €1,000,000 the waiver will need to

be approved by the European Banking Authority (EBA).

The imposition of a bonus-to-salary ratio has actually caused vigorous discussions and

reactions especially in the UK, prompting the Government to lodge a complaint with the

European Court of Justice (ECJ). Further concern is caused by the circumstance that the

FSA as a consequence of the introduction of new laws usually amend regulations, in this

case the Remuneration Code, imposing more stringent and cogent regulations vis-à-vis

its European counterparts.

As Nava (2011) pointed out, in order to avoid the repetition of international financial

crises European countries should all have the same rules and this objective can only be

attained by means of a common regulation. This is clearly supportable, but European

regulations do not indeed apply to the United States, Australia and the Asian countries.

The best European talents, because of the weakening of the variable reward packages,

that is bonuses, European banks and financial institutions can offer them, could opt to

join American and Asian employers lured by the attractive reward packages these are

still able to offer. Indeed, the unprecedented EU Parliament move could hopefully push

the American Congress and the Asian lawmakers and regulators to follow suit but, at the

moment in time, there is no evidence that this is within their plans.

The UK government and financial sector fierce opposition to the new provisions is

obviously justified; its introduction can remarkably weaken the City attractiveness and

appeal at global level. As highlighted by Browne (2013), London is not representative of

the UK’s banks only, but rather of all of the international banks based in Europe, which

387

Making the case for and against variable pay

are usually operating from London. According to the EBA, in 2012 the number of “high

earners” in the UK has increased from 2,436 to 2,714, compared to the 212 high earners

recorded in Germany, the 177 in France and the roughly 100 high earners existing in

Italy and Spain (Clinch, 2013). The central role of London within Europe is clearly not

threatened; talents from across Europe have always moved to London and will possibly

continue to do so, provided these would not decide to better move to New York, Tokyo,

Singapore or Hong Kong in order to receive larger financial reward packages.

As we have seen above, the EU CRD IV, in a bid to make more unlikely or less relevant

the eventual public intervention in case of other financial crises, introduced regulations

prescribing banks stricter capital requirements and better liquidity management. The

objective of these rules is clearly that to force banks and financial institutions to keep on

board some parachutes. The fact is that banks practically have to pay for these

parachutes, with the immediate consequence that they will have less money to invest

available to them. In order to continue to be productive and not reduce the productivity

levels to which banks are used, these should attain better ROI rates. All of that, as

appropriately suggested by Wright (2011), could just have the effect to increase the

temptation to favour short-term risk investments.

The question is: can actually regulations help to definitely address the problem?

According to Cotton (2011), regulations can have a limited effect in that they are

normally retrospectively drafted, in the sense that they tend to settle problems when

these have already occurred; as such, regulations are not likely to prevent the impact

that unexpected new circumstances may produce. This entails that whether in the future

a financial crisis should burst because of different-related reasons, the current

regulations could